This is an old revision of the document!


Game Theory

Game theory is a mathematical framework for modeling and analyzing situations in which decision-makers interact to maximize their own interests. It is used to study decision-making in various fields such as economics, political science, psychology, and biology. The theory considers the strategic interdependence between players and provides methods for predicting and explaining the outcome of interactions in different types of games, such as cooperative and non-cooperative games. Some of the key concepts in game theory include Nash equilibrium, the prisoner's dilemma, and bargaining solutions.

Zero-sum game theory is a branch of game theory where the total benefit or gain of all players in the game is equal to zero. In other words, in a zero-sum game, one player's gain is exactly balanced by the losses of the other players. The concept is based on the idea that the total benefit of a game remains constant and that any gain by one player must come at the expense of another player.

Examples of zero-sum games include chess, poker, and rock-paper-scissors. In these games, one player's win results in the loss of the other player, and the total winnings and losses balance out to zero. In poker, for instance, if one player wins a hand, the other players must have lost that same amount.

In contrast, non-zero-sum games, such as many real-world economic and political interactions, do not have a constant total benefit. In these games, the actions of one player can increase the total benefit for all players, such as in a cooperative game where players work together to achieve a common goal.

In zero-sum games, the concept of the Nash Equilibrium is often used to analyze and predict the outcome of the game. The Nash Equilibrium is a state in which each player's strategy is optimal given the strategies of the other players, and no player has the incentive to change their strategy. In a zero-sum game, the Nash Equilibrium represents the most balanced outcome, with one player's gain being exactly offset by the losses of the other players.

A positive-sum game is one in which the total benefit or gain of all players in the game is greater than zero. In other words, in a positive-sum game, the collective benefit of all players is increased as a result of their interaction.

Positive-sum games are often characterized by cooperation and mutual benefit, where the actions of one player can lead to increased benefits for all players. For example, trade between countries can be seen as a positive-sum game, where both countries benefit from the exchange of goods and services. Another example is a cooperative game, where players work together to achieve a common goal, and each player's efforts increase the overall benefit for all players.

In contrast to zero-sum games, positive-sum games have the potential to create mutual benefits and create a more prosperous outcome for all players involved. However, they also present challenges in terms of finding solutions that are fair and equitable to all players, and in overcoming obstacles such as mistrust, self-interest, and conflicting objectives.

Negative-sum game theory is a branch of game theory where the total benefit or gain of all players in the game is less than zero. In other words, in a negative-sum game, the collective losses of all players are greater than their collective gains.

Negative-sum games often occur in situations where resources are scarce, and the actions of one player lead to a decrease in the resources available for others. For example, a war between two countries can be seen as a negative-sum game, where both countries suffer losses in terms of lives, resources, and economic damage, and the total benefits of the conflict are less than zero. Another example is a prisoner's dilemma, where the cooperative solution would result in a positive sum outcome, but the rational self-interested behavior of each player results in a negative sum outcome for all.

Negative-sum games present challenges in terms of finding solutions that lead to a more positive outcome for all players involved. They often require cooperation, compromise, and a willingness to sacrifice individual benefits for the collective good.

The prisoner's dilemma is a classic example of a non-cooperative game in game theory, used to illustrate the conflicts that can arise from rational self-interest. It is a two-player game that models a situation in which two individuals are accused of a crime and are held in separate cells, unable to communicate with each other.

In the game, each player must decide whether to confess or remain silent. If both players confess, they both receive a severe punishment. If both players remain silent, they receive a lesser punishment. If one player confesses and the other remains silent, the player who confesses receives a reduced punishment while the other player receives a severe punishment.

The logic of the prisoner's dilemma is based on the idea that each player will act in their own self-interest and try to minimize their punishment. However, when both players act in this manner, they end up with a worse outcome than if they had both remained silent. This creates a situation in which rational self-interest leads to an undesirable outcome for both players.

Examples of the prisoner's dilemma can be found in a variety of real-world situations, such as international relations, business competition, and environmental policy. For example, in international relations, two countries may both have the option to build up their military or reduce their military spending. If both countries build up their military, they both face the risk of war and increased military spending. If both countries reduce their military spending, they both benefit from peace and decreased military spending. However, if one country builds up its military and the other reduces its military spending, the country that builds up its military will be more secure, while the other country will be less secure.

The prisoner's dilemma provides a powerful illustration of the challenges and conflicts that can arise from rational self-interest and the importance of cooperation in achieving mutually beneficial outcomes.

There are many other examples of game theory, some of which are:

  • Chicken: This is a game in which two drivers race towards each other on a collision course. The driver who swerves first is the loser, while the driver who continues straight on is the winner.
  • Tragedy of the Commons: This is a game in which multiple individuals share a common resource, such as a fishery or a forest, and must decide how much of the resource to extract. If all individuals extract as much as they can, the resource becomes depleted and everyone is worse off.
  • Stag Hunt: This is a game in which two individuals must decide whether to hunt a stag or a hare. Hunting a stag requires cooperation, while hunting a hare can be done individually. If one person hunts a stag and the other hunts a hare, the person who hunted the stag will be left empty-handed.
  • Battle of the Sexes: This is a game in which a couple must decide whether to attend a ballet or a football game. If they both attend the same event, they are both happy. If they attend different events, they will both be unhappy.
  • Ultimatum Game: This is a game in which one player must make a proposal for how to divide a sum of money between the two players. The other player must then decide whether to accept or reject the proposal. If the proposal is rejected, both players receive nothing.

These games illustrate different aspects of game theory and decision-making, and are used to study various aspects of human behavior, including cooperation, competition, fairness, and bargaining.

You could leave a comment if you were logged in.
  • Last modified: 2023/02/04 08:06
  • by andrewtaustin